The Risks of Raising 401(k) Default-Savings Rates

Research August 28, 2023 at 06:53 PM
Share & Print

Higher default savings rates and more aggressive default allocations made possible by the Pension Protection Act of 2006 have been a major trend in the world of 401(k) plans, with numerous analyses showing the positive affect both of these changes have had on the average American saver.

Given the broader adoption of higher defaults, a new study published by the National Bureau of Economic Research asks some natural questions: How high is too high for the default? And what happens if an employer only matches contributions made at very high rates in an attempt to encourage greater savings?

Specifically, the study reviews a real-world case study where a retirement savings plan adopted a default rate of 12% of income for new hires, which is much higher than previously studied defaults. Another distinguishing feature of the plan is that only contributions made above the 12% mark receive the employer match, with the theory being that these combined features should inspire very high levels of savings.

The paper, however, suggests this theory may be flawed, as by the end of the first year of the experiment, only 25% of employees had not opted out of this default. A subsequent literature review included in the analysis finds that the corresponding fraction of "opt-outs" in plans with lower defaults in the realm of 6% is approximately 50%.

The analysis was put together by a team of five NBER-affiliated researchers that included John Beshears and David Laibson of the Harvard Business School, Ruofei Guo of Northwestern University, Brigitte Madrian at Brigham Young University and James Choi of the Yale School of Management.

As the researchers summarize, in large part because only those contributions above 12% were matched by the employer, 12% was likely to be a suboptimal contribution rate for employees. Furthermore, employees who remained at the 12% default contribution rate unexpectedly had average income that was approximately one-third lower than would be predicted from the relationship between salaries and contribution rates among employees who were not at 12%.

The results, according to the researchers, suggest defaults appear to influence low-income employees more strongly, in part because these employees face higher psychological barriers to active decision-making and often fall prey to procrastination and inertia.

Whatever the case, the researchers conclude, simply pushing default contributions rates higher and higher does not appear to represent a realistic solution to the nation's retirement savings shortfall, as even those with sufficient means to save at this level are often turned away.

While focused on the workplace, the findings are of growing relevance to the wealth management community as leading firms seek to expand their defined contribution capabilities to access a lucrative and growing market.

Key Details From the Analysis

As noted, the analysis looks at the real-world experience of an employer that modified its retirement plan to include a 12% default contribution rate for new hires. The firm did not make any matching contributions on the first 12% of pay contributed by the employee, but instead matched the next 6% of pay contributed at a 100% marginal match rate.

According to the researchers, this default was not only considerably higher than previously studied defaults, but it was also likely to be a suboptimal contribution rate for employees — and this fact shows in the results.

"The figures indicate that employees opted out of the default rapidly," the researchers note. "By tenure month three, only 35% of the employees had never opted out of the default, and this fraction steadily declined to 25% by tenure month 12."

As a point of contrast, the paper cites various prior analyses that show 33% to 71% of employees remained at the default contribution rate at roughly comparable time horizons when the default is set between 1% and 6%.

Of the employees who opted out of the 12% default contribution rate, 74% chose a rate lower than 12% in tenure month 12.

"Consistent with the findings of previous studies, many employees contributed the minimum amount required to receive the maximum employer match," the paper notes. "In this case, 10% of the sample had a contribution rate of 18%. However, 31% of the sample chose a contribution rate of 4%, which was the lowest officially permissible rate for employees who wished to remain active plan participants."

Notably, the distribution of contribution rates has little mass immediately to the left or right of 12%, the researchers point out. This implies that many employees who opted out of the default rejected the 12% contribution rate decisively, instead of adjusting their contribution rates incrementally.

Takeaways for Financial Professionals

The researchers say one surprising data point that deserves additional contemplation is the fact that employees who had a 12% contribution rate at 12 months of tenure had salaries that were approximately one-third lower than what would be predicted from the salaries of employees who had chosen non-default contribution rates.

"Our analysis suggests that barriers to active decision-making, such as a tendency to procrastinate or a lack of domain-relevant knowledge, played some role in low-income employees' higher likelihood of remaining at the default," the paper notes.

While it may sound like a good thing that these lower-income workers remained so "committed" to higher savings rates, the reality is that they are likely saving at sub-optimal rates that could leave them exposed to the risks of unexpected emergency expenses and higher levels of debt. In other words, many who remain at the default may be better off from a consumption-smoothing perspective by reducing their savings level, but they fail to take action.

The researchers go on to emphasize that, beyond the default savings level, the specific structure of employer matching contributions is an important determinant of behaviors.

"[Our] study implies that the default contribution rate of 12% was unlikely to be the ideal contribution rate from the perspective of any individual employee," the authors note. "However, the default contribution rate of 12% might have been a wise policy for a social planner to adopt. It prompted many employees to opt out, and those employees might have had sufficient knowledge to select the contribution rates that were best suited to their individual circumstances."

The authors say future work should be undertaken to analyze the consequences of high default contribution rates for consumption and retirement plan balances over the long run to better understand the implications for savers' welfare.

Credit: Adobe Stock

NOT FOR REPRINT

© 2024 ALM Global, LLC, All Rights Reserved. Request academic re-use from www.copyright.com. All other uses, submit a request to [email protected]. For more information visit Asset & Logo Licensing.

Related Stories

Resource Center