This week's release of President Donald Trump's budget, with its draconian cuts to the social safety net and unrealistic projections of future growth, has again shined a light on our fiscal challenges. The U.S. clearly needs additional tax revenue to fund vital programs and investments that underlie future economic growth. As no single tax instrument, by itself, is likely to suffice, a number of incremental measures will be required. In this spirit, three Democratic presidential candidates have proposed a financial transaction tax (FTT) to help fund their proposed investments in health care, education, and infrastructure. If properly designed, an FTT would raise substantial revenue, in a progressive fashion, without impeding price discovery or the efficient allocation of capital.
An FTT is a small tax that would apply to trading in stocks, bonds, and derivatives. For example, an FTT of 10 basis points (0.10%) would result in a $10 tax for every $10,000 in stock sold.
This idea is not new. The United Kingdom has had an FTT in the form of a stamp duty since 1694, and several other countries have a version of an FTT now. There are notable successes. Hong Kong raises significant revenue, equivalent to more than 1% of gross domestic product, through its FTT while serving as a critical global financial center. Badly designed FTTs have also produced infamous failures, such as in the case of Sweden, which repealed its excessive FTT in 1991.
The United States can learn from these examples. As set forth in a proposal I recently co-authored with Laura Kawano of the University of Michigan's Ross School of Business, we recommend a tax of 10 basis points on the trading of equities and most bonds and derivatives. There would be some exclusions, notably for Treasuries and money market instruments. The FTT would include provisions to limit tax avoidance through offshore trading and should be implemented in coordination with other countries. Administrative costs also should be relatively low. In the case of equities, systems already exist to collect a small fee that funds the Securities and Exchange Commission.
Because the United States does not have recent experience with a nontrivial FTT, we recommend the tax be phased-in over four years, starting at 2 basis points and increasing annually. This lag would allow policymakers to calibrate the FTT based on actual data on market effects and avoidance techniques that will inevitably arise.
Why 10 basis points? The FTT is a transaction cost, and relative to current costs, most markets appear capable of absorbing the increase over time. In fact, in many markets a 10 basis point FTT would be less than recent declines in transaction costs. As such, it may simply return costs to levels that prevailed less than a decade ago. While some have argued for an FTT as high as half a percent, such levels appear too high relative to current costs and are unlikely to increase revenue, as an analysis by the Tax Policy Center suggests.
Even at 10 basis points, an FTT would raise significant revenue due to the high volume of financial market transactions. Estimates by the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center suggest that the FTT we propose would raise just over $500 billion in its first 10 years and, once fully phased in, $60 billion annually.