Academic macroeconomists almost never try to make forecasts about the macroeconomy. That probably sounds almost unbelievable to most people, but it's true — look at any macro paper in a mainstream economic journal, and there's only a very small chance that it will be about forecasting. There are one or two economists out there who are deeply interested in the reason for this, and a small trickle of promising papers. And some economists do pay attention to their models' forecasting performance. But the vast majority of research is about predicting the effects of policies, rather than about predicting what will actually happen.
This might seem like a dereliction of duty. Many, such as the Queen of England, expect that economists should be able to see recessions coming — or at least to try. After all, weather forecasters try to predict storms and heat waves, right?
Academic economists will give varying explanations for why they don't pay much attention to forecasting, but the core reason is that it's very, very hard to do. Unlike weather, where Doppler radar and other technology gathers fine-grained details on air currents, humidity and temperature, macroeconomics is traditionally limited to a few noisy variables like gross domestic product, investment, consumption and consumer price indexes, collected only at low frequencies and whose very definitions rely on a number of questionable assumptions. And unlike weather, where models are underpinned by laws of physics good enough to land astronauts on the moon, macroeconomics has only a patchy, poor understanding of individual human behavior. Even the most modern macro models, supposedly based on the actions of individual actors, typically forecast the economy no better than ultra-simple models with only one equation.
With inferior data and inferior theory, perhaps it's not surprising that macroeconomists would throw up their hands. There's also a cynical interpretation — policy recommendations are a lot harder to falsify, while with forecasting everyone knows when you get it wrong.
Whatever the reason, the field of macroeconomic forecasting is now exclusively the domain of central bankers, government workers and private-sector economists and consultants. But academics should try to get back in the game, because a powerful new tool is available that might be a game-changer. That tool is machine learning.
Loosely speaking, machine learning refers to a collection of algorithmic methods that focus on predicting things as accurately as possible instead of modeling them precisely. Instead of traditional statistics, where statisticians build models of how the world works, machine learning algorithms are generally given the freedom to figure out the model on their own. The downside is that it's often hard to tell exactly why the algorithms make the predictions they make, but the upside is that they are generally more accurate than traditional methods. In recent years, a type of algorithm known as deep learning has made incredible strides in a number of fields. Deep-learning algorithms, often marketed as artificial intelligence, can now beat humans at complex board games and operate self-driving cars.
Economists love new tools, and machine learning is no exception. Pioneering researchers like Susan Athey, Guido Imbens and Sendhil Mullainathan have figured out ways to use algorithms to help improve the statistical methods used to identify cause and effect in economics. That required some ingenuity, since identifying causality is all about determining the structure of the economy, whereas machine learning usually focuses on predicting things without knowing as much about the structure.