Is It the Spending or the Taxes? It's a Bit of Both

April 16, 2018 at 04:26 AM
Share & Print

Businessman with ball and chain (Image: Shutterstock)

The U.S. appears to face a future of large, chronic federal budget deficits. Is that because taxes are too low or because spending is too high?

In one sense, the question can only be answered with a value judgment — possibly but not necessarily informed by economic evidence — about the appropriate size of government. A commonly used alternative, though, is just to look at past taxing and spending and see whether current or expected levels are way out of line. The choice of time period is to some extent its own value judgment, of course, but it has become common practice in the U.S. to look at post-World War II averages to get some sense of what the "norm" is.

So let's do that! Federal spending since 1946 has averaged 19.3% of gross domestic product, while revenue has averaged 17.2%. Yes, that's a recipe for chronic deficits, but in a growing economy, a deficit of 2.1% of GDP is quite manageable, and compatible with a federal debt that is shrinking in relation to the overall economy. Sure enough, federal debt held by the public has fallen from 106.1% of GDP in 1946 to 76.5% of GDP as of the end of the 2017 fiscal year on Sept. 31. (The drop is less dramatic if you look at gross federal debt, which includes money owed to the Social Security trust funds and has gone from 118.9% in 1946 to 105.4% in 2017.)

How do current and projected spending levels compare? In the 2017 fiscal year, spending was 20.8% of GDP and revenue 17.3 percent; by fiscal 2019, this year's spending deal and last year's tax cuts are expected to bring spending up to 21.2% of GDP and revenue down to 16.5%, according to projections released this week by the Congressional Budget Office. Spending has departed from the post-war norm more than revenue has. And if you look decades into the future, as the CBO last did about a year ago, spending is set to get much further out of line — rising to a projected 29.4% of GDP by 2047.

So when Manhattan Institute budget wonk Brian Riedl argues that "Social Security and Medicare's shortfalls overwhelmingly cause the coming long-term debt," and Hoover Institution economist John Cochrane states that "entitlement spending" on Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid and such is "the central budget problem," they have a point!

Both were making these arguments in response to a Washington Post op-ed by five economists — Martin Neil Baily, Jason Furman, Alan B. Krueger, Laura D'Andrea Tyson and Janet L. Yellen — who all happen to have led the White House Council of Economic Advisers under Democratic presidents. Those five economists were in turn writing in critique of yet another Washington Post op-ed by Cochrane and four other Hoover Institution economists, all of whom (not including Cochrane) have held posts in Republican administrations.

The Republican economists' op-ed was about the threat of a "debt crisis" brought on by the "long-run entitlement explosion" described above. I found its downplaying and misrepresentation of the role played by last year's tax cuts in the growth of deficits irritating, so I too wrote a column critiquing it. But my response, and that of the five Democratic economists, also turns out to have downplayed and misrepresented something important: the likely future cost of Medicare.

Add up the current intermediate projections of the Social Security and Medicare trustees, I wrote, "and you get a funding deficit that rises from 0.1% of gross domestic product in 2017 to 1.7% in 2035 and fluctuates between 1.6% and 1.8% for the rest of the century." The Democratic economists never offered a number for the Social Security deficit, but they did mention "the Medicare Trustees' projections of a 0.3% of GDP shortfall in Medicare hospital insurance over the next 75 years."

That doesn't sound bad at all. But Medicare hospital insurance, also known as Part A, only accounted for 42% of the program's costs in 2016. The rest of the money went to Part B, which covers non-hospital medical services, and Part D, the prescription drug benefit added by Congress and President George W. Bush in 2003. And while Part A is paid for out of Medicare payroll taxes, which currently more than cover the costs but are projected to come up slightly short starting in 2021 or 2022, Parts B and D are paid for mainly out of general government revenues. So while there is something called the Supplementary Medical Insurance Trust Fund out of which Parts B and D are financed, estimates of its future adequacy are totally meaningless in fiscal-policy terms because they simply assume that transfers from general revenue will rise to meet costs.

Much more useful are the CBO's estimates of future Medicare costs, which strip out the misleading trust fund stuff. They show Medicare spending going from 3.1% of GDP in 2017 to 6.1% in 2047. That's a big increase!

It is also highly dependent on assumptions about the future growth of health care costs, which is why health care reform is probably a better framework for thinking about how to rein in those costs than "entitlement reform" is. With Social Security spending, which the CBO expects to grow from 5% of GDP in 2017 to 6.3% in 2047, modest cuts in promised future benefits do seem appropriate, although I tend to agree with the Democratic economists in the op-ed cited above that some additional revenue would be a good idea too "because Social Security has become even more vital as fewer and fewer people have defined-benefit pensions."

Finally, let's move on to a line item in the chart above that hasn't been mentioned yet: net interest. The CBO expects spending on it to go up a lot — 4.8% of GDP — between 2017 and 2047. That's not much less than the 5.2-percent-of-GDP expected rise in Social Security and health care spending, and well more than the projected 3.9-percent-of-GDP rise in overall non-interest federal spending (government spending on everything but Social Security and health care is expected to decline as a share of GDP). Part of that increase in net interest expenditures is because the CBO expects interest rates paid on Treasury securities to normalize after dropping to extremely low levels in the aftermath of the financial crisis; part can be attributed to the growing debt load that will result if revenues fail to keep up with outlays.

It's important to remember, though, that the level of revenue is a political choice, not some immutable law of economics. Other wealthy countries get by with much higher tax burdens than the U.S., without major differences in per-capita GDP growth. And while bringing revenue to within 2.1 GDP percentage points (the average deficit since World War II, which is clearly sustainable) of the 29.4% of GDP in spending projected for 2027 would require a hard-to-fathom 59% increase in the tax burden from the 17.2-percent-of-GDP postwar average, increasing taxes would also reduce interest costs. Cut out that 4.8-percent-of-GDP projected increase in interest spending, and the tax burden would have to go up 31% — still a lot, but much more manageable.

I would hope we could keep the tax hikes much smaller than that. But I don't think it's realistic to expect the country to get through the retirement of the baby boomers and the population aging that is likely to continue even after the boomers are gone at the current level of tax revenue. Spending is too high and taxes are too low.

— For more columns from Bloomberg View, visit http://www.bloomberg.com/view.


Justin Fox

Justin Fox is a Bloomberg View columnist. He was the editorial director of Harvard Business Review and wrote for Time, Fortune and American Banker. He is the author of "The Myth of the Rational Market."

NOT FOR REPRINT

© 2024 ALM Global, LLC, All Rights Reserved. Request academic re-use from www.copyright.com. All other uses, submit a request to [email protected]. For more information visit Asset & Logo Licensing.

Related Stories

Resource Center